Skip to content

Commit

Permalink
sync
Browse files Browse the repository at this point in the history
  • Loading branch information
keithalewis committed Apr 21, 2024
1 parent 7711940 commit 2203418
Show file tree
Hide file tree
Showing 2 changed files with 77 additions and 12 deletions.
2 changes: 1 addition & 1 deletion um0.md
Original file line number Diff line number Diff line change
Expand Up @@ -22,7 +22,7 @@ What volatiltiy should be used for valuing an option?
After putting on a hedge, when should that be adjusted?
How well will a hedging strategy perform?

This note does not solve these problems. It proposes a rigorous
This note does not solve these problems. It only proposes a rigorous
mathematical framework to allow for quantitative discussions.
We use stochastic processes to model market instrument prices and cash
flows but have no need for Brownian motion, much less Ito processes.
Expand Down
87 changes: 76 additions & 11 deletions um1.md
Original file line number Diff line number Diff line change
@@ -1,10 +1,10 @@
---
title: Unified Model for Derivative Instruments
title: Unified Model
author: Keith A. Lewis
institute: KALX, LLC
fleqn: true
classoption: fleqn
abstract: Value, hedge, and manage the risk of any instruments
abstract: Value, hedge, and manage the risk of instruments
...

\newcommand{\RR}{\boldsymbol{R}}
Expand All @@ -13,40 +13,105 @@ abstract: Value, hedge, and manage the risk of any instruments
\newcommand{\Var}{\operatorname{Var}}
\newcommand{\Cov}{\operatorname{Cov}}

Let $T$ be trading times, $I$ the set of all market instruments, $\Omega$ the sample space of possible outcomes,
and $(A_t)_{t\in T}$ be algebras of sets on $\Omega$ indicating the information available at each trading time.
A mathematical model for any set of instruments that can be used to value,
hedge, and understand how poorly risk-neutral pricing can be used for
managing risk.

Stephen Ross...

## Unified Model

Let $T$ be the set of trading times, $I$ the set of all market
instruments, $\Omega$ the sample space of possible outcomes, and
$(\AA_t)_{t\in T}$ be algebras of sets on $\Omega$ indicating the
information available at each trading time.

If $\AA$ is a finite algebra of sets on $\Omega$ then
the _atoms_ of $\AA$, $\bar{\AA}$, form a partition of $\Omega$.
A function $X\colon\Omega\to\RR$ is $\AA$ measurable if and
only if it is constant on atoms of $\AA$
so $X\colon\bar{\AA}\to\RR$ is a function.

### Market

_Price_ - market price assuming perfect liquidity
: $X_t\colon\AA_t\to\RR^I$
: $X_t\colon\bar{\AA_t}\to\RR^I$

_Cash flow_ - dividends, coupons, margin adjustments for futures
: $C_t\colon\AA_t\to\RR^I$
: $C_t\colon\bar{\AA_t}\to\RR^I$

### Trading

_Trading Strategy_ - increasing stopping times
: $\tau_0 < \cdots < \tau_n$ and trades $\Gamma_j\colon\AA_{\tau_j}\to\RR^I$

_Position_ - accumulate trades not including last trade
: $\Delta_t = \sum_{\tau_j < t}\Gamma_j = \sum_{s < t} \Gamma_s$

### Valuation

_Value_ - mark-to-market including last trade
: $V_t = (\Delta_t + \Gamma_t)\cdot X_t$

_Account_ - trading account blotter
: $A_t = \Delta_t\cdot C_t - \Gamma_t\cdot X_t$

### Arbitrage

_Arbitrage_ exists if there is a trading strategy
with $A_{\tau_0} > 0$, $A_t \ge 0$, $t > \tau_0$, and $\sum_{j} \Gamma_j = 0$.

The Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing states there is no arbitrage if and only
if there exist positive measures $D_t\colon\AA_t\to(0,\infty)$, ${t\in T}$ on $\Omega$ with
if there exist _deflators_, positive measures $D_t\colon\AA_t\to(0,\infty)$, ${t\in T}$ on $\Omega$, with
$$
X_t D_t = (X_u D_u + \sum_{t < s \le u} C_s D_s)|_{\AA_t}
\tag{1} X_t D_t = (X_u D_u + \sum_{t < s \le u} C_s D_s)|{\AA_t}
$$
where $|$ indicates restriction of measure to a subalgebra of sets.

__Lemma__. If $X_t D_t = M_t - \sum_{s\le t} C_s D_s$ where $M_t = M_u|{\AA_t}$, $t \le u$,
then there is no arbitrage.

__Lemma__. For any arbitrage free model and any trading strategy
$$
V_t D_t = (V_u D_u + \sum_{t < s \le u} A_s D_s)|_{\AA_t}
\tag{2} V_t D_t = (V_u D_u + \sum_{t < s \le u} A_s D_s)|{\AA_t}
$$

__Lemma__. If $X_t D_t = M_t - \sum_{s\le t} C_s D_s$ where $M_t = M_u|_{\AA_t}$, $t \le u$,
then there is no arbitrage.
Note how the value $V_t$ corresponds to price $X_t$ and account $A_t$
corresponds to $C_t$ in equations (2) and (1) respectively.
Trading strategies create synthetic market instruments.
This is the skeleton key to pricing derivative securities.

## Application

Suppose a derivative security specifies amounts $\bar{A}_j$ be paid at times $\bar{\tau}_j$.
If there is a trading strategy $(\tau_j, \Gamma_j)$
with $A_{\bar{\tau}_j} = \bar{A}_j$ for all $j$ and $A_t = 0$ otherwise (aka self-financing) then
a "perfect hedge" exists[^1].
The value of the derivative is the cost of setting up the initial hedge.

Note $V_t D_t= (\sum_{\tau_j > t} \bar{A}_j D_{\bar{\tau_j}})|\AA_t$
can be computed from the deriviative contract specification and the deflators $D_t$.
Since $V_t = (\Delta_t + \Gamma_t)\cdot X_t$
we have $\Delta_t + \Gamma_t$, is the Frechet derivative $D_{X_t}V_t$
of option value with respect to $X_t$.

If time $T = \{t_j\}$ is discrete we can compute a possible hedge at each time,
$\Gamma_j = D_{X_j}V_j - \Delta_j$, since $\Delta_j$ is known at $t_{j-1}$.
In general this hedge will not exactly replicate the derivative contract obligations.

[^1]: Perfect hedges never exist.

### Deflator

If repurchase agreements are available then a _canonical deflator_ exists.
A repurchase agreement over the interval $[t_j, t_{j+}]$ is specified
by a rate $f_j$ known at time $t_j$. The price at $t_j$ is $1$ and it
has a cash flow of $\exp(f_j(t_{j+1} - t_j))$ at time $t_{j+1}$.
By equation (1) we have $D_j = \exp(f_j\Delta t_j)D_{j+1}|\AA_j$.
If $D_{j+1}$ is known at time $t_j$ then $D_{j+1}/D_j = \exp(-f_j\Delta t_j)$ and
$D_j = \exp(-\sum_{i < j}f_i\Delta t_i)$ is the canonical deflator.

### Binomial Model



0 comments on commit 2203418

Please sign in to comment.